A new vision for agriculture
momagri, movement for a world agricultural organization, is a think tank chaired by Pierre Pagesse.
It brings together, managers from the agricultural world and important people from external perspectives,
such as health, development, strategy and defense. Its objective is to promote regulation
of agricultural markets by creating new evaluation tools, such as economic models and indicators,
and by drawing up proposals for an agricultural and international food policy.
surproduction
Point of view

Farmers have consistently produced themselves out of prosperity
what about this time?



Daryll E. Ray et Harwood D. Schaffer
Agricultural Policy Analysis Center (APAC)


Anticipating price levels for agricultural produce has become a game that fewer and fewer experts want to risk. Like it or not, the simple comparison of physical supply and demand is not sufficient to explain price movements. Increasing uncertainty in agricultural markets in a context of extreme global crisis has demonstrated the emergence of new destabilizing factors, such as increased speculation and has made expectations more risky and uncertain. As emphasized by Daryll E. Ray and Harwood D. Schaffer of the Agricultural Policy Analysis Center (APAC)1, farmers are all faced with the problem. Indeed, they are unable to precisely predict production levels and prices. This is one of the characteristics of agricultural markets. Underlining on the one hand the fact that profitable prices encourage production which eventually leads to an increase in supply, and on the other hand, the demand of emerging countries is at risk of being diminished as these countries develop their own agriculture, Daryll E. Ray and Harwood D. Schaffer wonder, in the light of these facts, if world agricultural prices will remain permanently high. Remembering that the CAP health check was built on this assumption...

momagri editorial board




In reading Jerry Hagstrom’s report on a 3-day conference, Agriculture Investment Summit for the Americas, we were struck by the witty insight of Jason Henderson when he said, “I have never met a farmer who is unwilling to produce himself [or herself] out of prosperity.”

In that one sentence, Henderson, executive vice president of the Omaha branch of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, summed up what agricultural economists have long known. Historically, the production of agricultural crops, sooner or later, outruns demand, resulting in multi-year periods of low prices. The same is true in the shorter-run for livestock, although producers there adjust production much more quickly than crop producers resulting what have historically been hog and cattle cycles.

This tendency towards over-production is not a new phenomenon in US agriculture. Shortly after the settlement of the first colonists in North America, farmers began to ship a new-fangled product called tobacco to London. Smoking caught on like wildfire—so to speak—and the production of tobacco became very lucrative.

The price was so lucrative that others quickly began to produce so much tobacco that within 40 years they had flooded the market. Prices fell so dramatically that several colonies were looking at acreage restrictions on the planting of tobacco in order to boost prices to a profitable level.

For a time, the production of indigo in the US South was profitable, but with increased production in the US, Central America, and South America, along with the advent of the Revolutionary War and the loss of the British per pound bonus, US producers could no longer compete and the domestic market collapsed, never to recover.

The pattern of profitable prices, followed by increased production and the addition of new production areas, resulting in long troughs of low prices has plagued the producers of corn, cotton, and wheat through much of US history, particularly following the Civil War and opening up of the Great Plains to crop agriculture. In the last century, this pattern was repeated following WWI, WWII, and the export boom of the 1970s.

We are now experiencing a similar boom and at the investing summit, Gerald Bange, Chair of USDA’s World Agricultural Outlook Board, told his audience “We’re not going to see $2 and $3 corn again in the” US. Much of his optimism is based on ethanol production and a growing export demand.

To date, agricultural exports to China, India, and Russia have been growing resulting in an ethanol/export led prosperity for US farmers. As Hagstrom reports (The Hagstrom Report, Oct. 24, 2011, Vol. 1 No. 194), Henderson cautioned his audience that “growing world markets may not always be there.”

Henderson based his caution on a look at the stages countries go through in the development process. In Stage One, a country begins to increase the importation of food just as Brazil did in the 1970s and Russia did with meat products in the 1990s.

Russia, along with China, is in Stage Two where they are seeking to “expand protein production with an eye toward feeding themselves and shrinking meat imports.” To do this they have increased their imports of soybean meal.

Brazil is now in Stage Three, a stage where they increase their production of crops so they no longer have to purchase imports to feed their own animals.

In Stage Four, a country begins to compete with their former suppliers, exporting both crops and protein. Brazil is there with regard to soybeans and is likely to soon be there when it comes to corn, wheat, beef, pork, and poultry.

If the pattern holds, Russia and China may not be too far behind.

1 http://www.agpolicy.org/weekcol/588.html
Page Header
Paris, 23 July 2014